Land Value Taxation: a fairer tax system?

TaxesWhen Gary Sandberg ran for at-large city councilman, one of the planks in his platform was that he’d like to see the city move toward “site value taxation.” No one asked what that was at any of the candidate forums I attended. I probably wouldn’t have heard about it again, except that I recently got a call from a gentleman named John Kelly. He’s an evangelist of sorts for this type of taxation, also known as “Land Value Taxation.”

After talking to him at length about it, I have to admit the idea has some merit. But I’d be interested in hearing what my readers think of it. Here’s a brief overview of how it works, as I understand it.

The current system

Our property taxes for the Taylor Private Estate in Swan Valley are based on what’s called the “assessed value” of property. The “assessed value” is about one-third of the property’s market value, so theoretically if you have a house that appraised at $150,000, its “assessed value” for taxing purposes would be $50,000.

The assessed value is made up of two parts: the value of the land, and the value of the improvements on that land. These two values are actually split out on your tax bill, so you can see how much each is worth for your property. The land value is the value of the lot all by itself with nothing on it. The improvements are any structures put up on the land, like houses, garages, commercial buildings, etc.

Here’s the point to remember: even though those two values are listed separately on your tax bill, they’re taxed at the same rate. This is called a “unified tax rate.” So, for instance, if the assessed value of your land is $5,000 and the assessed value of your improvements is $37,000, and your tax rate is 8%, you pay $400 in taxes on your land and $2,960 in taxes on your improvements. With me so far?

Proponents of land value taxation would point out several flaws in this system. The most basic one is the one every homeowner knows: if you make improvements to your property, you get a big property tax increase. Say you buy a house for $20,000 (market value). You put new siding on it, replace the porch and the furnace, add central air, put on a new roof, and now the property is worth $55,000 (market value). The tax assessor makes a note of it, and when you get your next tax bill, you see your taxes have almost tripled, from $533 to $1,467.

We’re so used to it, we’ve probably never even questioned it. That’s just the way it is. You do something good and get penalized for it. No good deed goes unpunished, right? But think about it for a second from the city’s perspective. What does this policy incentivize? It’s a deterrent to fixing up your property, isn’t it? Is that good for the city? Don’t we want people to fix up their properties? Could the fact that our tax policy discourages improvements be one reason there are so many rental properties in disrepair?

The “land value taxation” system

Under a land value taxation strategy, land and improvements would be taxed at different rates. Under its purest form, improvements wouldn’t be taxed at all — only the land would. But proponents aren’t suggesting anything that radical to start. They propose instead that the tax rate be raised on land and lowered on improvements.

Why? Well, the theoretical reason is this: the land (not the improvements) increases in value because of what the city/county/community brings to it, not what the individual does to improve it. Its access to infrastructure (roads, sewers, water, sidewalks, gas, etc.), the demand created due to (a) improvements made to surrounding properties and (b) the general residential/business climate created by the city through its economic development policies, police/fire services, etc. — these things give the land its value, regardless of what the owner of the land does to it. The owner of the property didn’t provide the infrastructure or the city services or improvements to the surrounding properties, but he reaps the benefits of those things through the value of his land. Since the community provides that value, it’s only fair to collect taxes from landowners who are profiting from those benefits in order to continue providing those benefits. The improvements, on the other hand, are the capital and equity the landowner puts into the property. The value added by the property owner himself should not be penalized.

That’s the theoretical reason. The practical reason is that it encourages a number of positive things that are good for the community.

First, it removes the disincentive for improving property that we talked about earlier. If you knew you weren’t going to get hit with a big property tax increase for building that new garage or sunroom, would you be more likely to build it? Of course you would.

Second, it encourages efficient land use (or, to put it another way, it discourages sprawl). Right now, a retail store with a big surface parking lot pays very little tax on that part of their land because an asphalt lot is not much of an “improvement” compared to putting a building on that land. But if the tax on land were higher than the tax on improvements, suddenly there’s an incentive to conserve land or use it more efficiently. Instead of building large one-story buildings with huge surface lots, this form of taxation would provide an incentive for making that a two- or three-story building with a parking deck. After all, those improvements aren’t going to be taxed as much as the land, so there’s more bang for your buck by conserving.

Third, it discourages land speculation and otherwise holding onto vacant land. If you have a lot that’s worth $60,000 and you’re only paying 8% property tax on it ($4,800/year), you’re more likely to hold onto it than if it were taxed at, say, 20% ($12,000/year). There would be an incentive for you to do something with that land — either build or sell.

Could it happen here?

According to John Kelly, a local stock broker who has done extensive research into this idea, state law does not allow a split rate at this time. There may be a way to work around that, but the law is ambiguous on it. The easiest way to enact a land value tax system would be for the state to pass legislation authorizing it for home rule communities like Peoria. However, the powers that be in Springfield won’t allow it to even be introduced.

The best bet was Dave Koehler, who was an advocate of land value taxation when he was a city councilman. However, he hasn’t proposed any legislation to allow it. If it were ever to become legal, Mayor Ardis believes there would interest in trying here in Peoria. When I e-mailed him recently to ask him his opinion on the idea, he had this to say:

We’d have to get Springfield to allow us to do this and he hasn’t been able to get a State Legislator interested in over 20 years. There may be interest on the council to explore this, but without support in [Springfield] it won’t happen and that’s probably why it has never been pushed.

So, what do you think of this idea, readers? Good idea? Bad idea? It’s a new idea for me, so I haven’t settled into a firm stance on it. Although it’s new to me, it’s not a new idea — it was first suggested by Henry George in his 1879 book “Progress and Poverty.” You can read more about it here, here, and here.

14 thoughts on “Land Value Taxation: a fairer tax system?”

  1. I’m going to try to refrain from writing a book here. There are probably far more people in certain parts of this city who are just too lazy to do anything to improve their homes, as homeowners or landlords, and they would spend their breaks on Schlitz (or in my case, Sam Adams) instead of shingles. There are those of us that would appreciate the gesture of not taxing the heck out of improvements. I have probably spent 50K on my house and it is one reason I have quit major improvements because my taxes have almost doubled in the 12 years I’ve owned my house. That said, most of the major, tax raising improvements are already made, so where does that leave me with land value taxation?

    I guess my question about land value taxation is this: what determines city improvements vs. general city maintenance? If the city re-paves Prospect, and I live off of Prospect, do may taxes go up for this improvement or do they remain the same because this is general maintenance? Sorry if sounds naive, just looking to learn more.

    I have a completely different idea\theory, but feel it is way too long to post here.

  2. Kevin –
    The assessor does not directly increase or decrease your values – the market does, and the assessor tries to recognize market values when he or she does the assessing. Assessors usually use recent sales to estimate what has happened to properties.
    So, if the city makes an improvement near your house, your assessment won’t change unless the market reacts to it.

  3. Could the city then also tier the land value rates based on the proportional cost of city services? Having higher rates in areas requiring higher public expense (police, fire, roads)? Or this this only reflected due to the fact larger lots (lower densitites) would pay more becuase they have more land?

  4. All those services are already in the land value, so the market has determined their value. There is no need for City Hall to further mastermind them.

    Remember too, that nearby private investment, things that create jobs, subdivisions, retail, etc., will add to land value as well. Separating only the public benefits would be problematic.

  5. Those service are assumed to be because of the realiability of local government, but the tax isn’t necessarily portional to the amount of services rendered. That’s my question. For example, if it costs more to serve houses in dunlap should they pay a different land value rate proportional to those services?

  6. Chief –
    How much of a Dunlap Homeowner’s land value is attributable to the access it has through the street system? How much of it is due to its proximity to CAT Mossville? What does the police department add? How about the library?

    I don’t know the specific answers to any of these questions, but I do know that the aggregate is all contained in the locational value that the home has.

  7. Question,
    if the city does not invest in infastructure improvements in your part of town, and/or it is a high crime area with safety concerns over the level of fire protection, and slumlords abound then your property taxes should drop significantly (much like the value of your home). Correct?

  8. CJ
    Very useful information, but probably on logical actions in view. I have always questioned, in my mind, the “penalty” for improving your home. It does not make sense. In that vein of thought, I also have always considered that IF you board up the windows on a vacant property, the taxes should be doubled. This woudl discourage people from doing that. It is bad for the neighborhood.

  9. I totally agree with this kind of assessment. I live in an older, lower tax neighborhood and plan to stay in my house for the next 40-50 years, so the property value rising is no incentive to me. But if I add an addition onto the house for my family’s use/enjoyment, paying more in taxes is a huge disincentive for me. I’m improving the neighborhood, why should I be punished for it. It’s not like the police cars are suddenly going to drive by more often or I’m going to get an extra trash pickup for it.

  10. There’s no reforming the property tax system. It should be abolished. It’s regressive, antiquated, complicated, subjective, in a word, UNFAIR. Get rid of it.

  11. Paul –
    The land values in the parts of town you mentioned refect those problems. Locational values in some parts of town are quite low.

    A Site Value Taxation system collects revenue today on site values, but it also creates promise for tomorrow, especially in the older parts of town.

    It incents some of those slum landlords to do the right thing because it lowers the penalty for doing so. It encourages infill. It tends to help bring older neighborhoods back, instead of penalizing revialization.

    Now these things will not happen overnight – it took many years to bring some of these neighborhoods to their current state. But the biggest changes will be seen in the older neighborhoods. As a general rule, owner occupied homes will see a small tax cut; slummy properties will see a bit of a tax increase. The new investment in either of those structures will have a significant tax reduction.

    Site Value Taxation pushes inner city areas to revitalize, without City Hall doing anything.

  12. I helped put together the Maryland (www.marylandlandtax.org)
    Indiana (www.indianalandvaluetax.org)and
    New Jersey (www.newjerseylandvaluetax.org)
    Land Value Tax Projects.

    The best way to see if LVT might play in Peoria
    is to get us the city assessment data and we’ll run the numbers so that people can see how it would actually work.

    John D. Kromkowski

  13. Sorry, John. The parcel-by-parcel assessment data for the entire city (about 65,000 parcels) is somehow unavailable. Even City Hall cannot get it. The City Assessor cannot access it, nor can the Mayor. The County has the info and will not release it. One can only speculate as to why this public information is so closely guarded.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.